Externalities from Concentrated Animal Feeding Operations

dc.contributor.authorBast, Ellen
dc.contributor.departmentEconomicsen_US
dc.contributor.programBachelor's Degreeen_US
dc.date.accessioned2016-02-12T19:34:18Z
dc.date.available2016-02-12T19:34:18Z
dc.date.issued2014
dc.descriptionJulia Rogers Research Prize: Junior/Senior Winner, 2014en_US
dc.description.abstractClassical economics is based upon three assumptions about the firms and individuals that partake in the market: they are goal-oriented, meaning that they are interested in fulfilling their own personal or private goals; they are rational, meaning that their behavior is the result of privately considered costs and benefits; and they must deal with scarce resources, meaning that there is not enough time, resources, or money to fulfill all of their wants and needs. That is, when individuals and firms operate and make decisions, they do so in a way that maximizes their personal utility given the constraints and limitations associated with finite resources. However, not all decision making can be viewed in isolation for each individual or firm. In many cases, decisions affect others. Instances such as these fall under the category of market failures, which are instances where the perfectly competitive market fails to produce a Pareto optimal amount or equilibrium. These can occur in exchange or production when a non-optimal allocation of scarce resources takes place. For example, the decision to donate blood has the benefit of potentially saving the life of three other people, in addition to securing access to possible future blood transfusions to the donor and his/her family. On the other hand, the decision to build an airport near a busy subdivision may result in noise pollution that damages the residents nearby. These benefits and costs that affect individuals other than the decision maker—these external effects—have been termed externalities and can be either positive or negative. Positive externalities produce a benefit to a party other than the decision maker, whereas negative externalities harm an otherwise uninvolved party (Browning and Zupan 2009). There are many applications of the theory of externalities in the economics literature of today; one such example examines the consequences of industrial agriculture, namely livestock production in concentrated animal feeding operations (CAFOs).en_US
dc.description.sponsorshipLydia Harrisen_US
dc.description.urihttp://blogs.goucher.edu/verge/files/2016/01/EC001_CR.pdf
dc.format.extent20 p.en_US
dc.genreresearch papersen_US
dc.identifierdoi:10.13016/M2H72G
dc.identifier.urihttp://hdl.handle.net/11603/2250
dc.language.isoen_USen_US
dc.relation.isAvailableAtGoucher College, Baltimore, MD
dc.rightsCollection may be protected under Title 17 of the U.S. Copyright Law. To obtain information or permission to publish or reproduce, please contact the Goucher Special Collections & Archives at 410-337-6347 or email archives@goucher.edu.
dc.titleExternalities from Concentrated Animal Feeding Operationsen_US
dc.typeTexten_US

Files

Original bundle
Now showing 1 - 1 of 1
Loading...
Thumbnail Image
Name:
JRRP2014_JunSen_Bast.pdf
Size:
96.97 KB
Format:
Adobe Portable Document Format
Description:
License bundle
Now showing 1 - 1 of 1
No Thumbnail Available
Name:
license.txt
Size:
1.6 KB
Format:
Item-specific license agreed upon to submission
Description: